Skip to main content

A package for solving, estimating, and analyzing DSGE models

Project description

gEconpy

A collection of tools for working with DSGE models in python, inspired by the fantastic R package gEcon, http://gecon.r-forge.r-project.org/.

Like gEcon, gEconpy solves first order conditions automatically, helping the researcher avoid math errors while facilitating rapid prototyping of models. By working in the optimization problem space rather than the FoC space, modifications to the model are much simpler. Adding an additional term to the utility function, for example, requires modifying only 2-3 lines of code, whereas in FoC space it may require re-solving the entire model by hand.

gEconpy uses the GCN file originally created for the gEcon package. gEcon GCN files are fully compatable with gEconpy, and includes all the great features of GCN files, including:

  • Automatically solve first order conditions
  • Users can include steady-state values in equations without explictly solving for them by hand first!
  • Users can declare "calibrated parameters", requesting a parameter value be found to induce a specific steady-state relationship

gEconpy is still in an unfinished alpha state, but I encourage anyone interested in DSGE modeling to give it a try and and report any bugs you might find.

Contributing:

Contributions from anyone are welcome, regardless of previous experience. Please check the Issues tab for open issues, or to create a new issue.

Representing a DSGE Model

Like the R package gEcon, gEconpy uses .GCN files to represent a DSGE model. A GCN file is divided into blocks, each of which represents an optimization problem. Here is one block from the example Real Business Cycle (RBC) model included in the package.

block HOUSEHOLD
{
	definitions
	{
		u[] = C[] ^ (1 - sigma_C) / (1 - sigma_C) -
		      L[] ^ (1 + sigma_L) / (1 + sigma_L);
	};

	controls
	{
		C[], L[], I[], K[];
	};

	objective
	{
		U[] = u[] + beta * E[][U[1]];
	};

	constraints
	{
		C[] + I[] = r[] * K[-1] + w[] * L[] : lambda[];
		K[] = (1 - delta) * K[-1] + I[] : q[];
	};

	calibration
	{
		# Fixed parameters
		beta  = 0.99;
		delta = 0.02;

		# Parameters to estimate
		sigma_C ~ N(loc=1.5, scale=0.1, lower=1.0) = 1.5;
		sigma_L ~ N(loc=2.0, scale=0.1, lower=1.0) = 2.0;
	};
};

Basic Basics

A .GCN file uses an easy-to-read syntax. Whitespace is not meaningful - lines are terminated with a ";", so long equations can be split into multiple lines for readability. There are no reserved keywords* to avoid -- feel free to write beta instead of betta!

Model variables are written with a name followed by square brackets, as in U[]. The square brackets give the time index the variable enters with. Following Dynare conventions, capital stock K[-1] enters with a lag, while all other variables enter in the present. Expectations are denoted by wrapping variables with E[], as in E[U[1]] for expected utility at t+1. So I lied, there are a couple reserved keywords (hence the asterisk). Finally, you can refer directly to steady-state values as K[ss].

Parameters are written exactly as variables, except they have no square brackets [].

Anatomy of a Block

Blocks are divided into five components: definitions, controls, objective, constraints, identities, shocks, and, calibration. In this block, we see five of the seven. The blocks have the following functions:

  1. definitions contains equations that are not stored in the model. Instead, they are immediately substituted into all equations within the same block. In this example, a definition is used for the instantaneous utility function. It will be immediately substitutited into the Bellman equation written in the objective block.
  2. controls are the variables under the agent's control. The objective function represented by the block will be solved by forming a Lagrange function and taking derivatives with respect to the controls.
  3. The objective block contains only a single equation, and gives the function an agent will try to maximize over an infinite time horizon. In this case, the agent has a CRRA utility function.
  4. constraints give the resource constraints that the agent's maximization must respect. All constraints are given their own Lagrange multipiers.
  5. identities are equations that are not part of an optimization problem, but that are a part of the model. Unlike equations defined in the definitions block, identities are saved in the model's system of equations.
  6. shocks are where the user defines exogenous shocks, as in varexo in Dynare.
  7. The calibration block where free parameters, calibrated parameters, and parameter prior distributions are defined.

Parameter Values and Priors

All parameters must be given values. In the household block above, all parameters are given a value directly. beta and delta are set fixed, while sigma_C and sigma_L are given priors and starting values. The ~ operator denotes a Prior, while = denotes a fixed value. All parameters must have a fixed value -- this is used as the "default" value when building and solving the model. Priors, on the other hand, are optional. At present, the user can choose from Normal, HalfNormal, TruncatedNormal, Beta, Gamma, Inverse_Gamma, and Uniform priors, with more to come as I improve the integration with PyMC. Distributons can be parameterized either using the loc, scale, shape synatx of scipy.stats, or directly using the common parameter values from the literature (such as a mu and sigma for a normal).

As an alterantive to setting a parameter value directly, the user can declare a parameter to be calibrated. To do this, give a steady-state relationship that the parameter should be calibrated to ensure is true. The following GCN code block for the firm's optimization problem shows how this is done:

block FIRM
{
    controls
    {
        K[-1], L[];
    };

    objective
    {
        TC[] = -(r[] * K[-1] + w[] * L[]);
    };

    constraints
    {
        Y[] = A[] * K[-1] ^ alpha * L[] ^ (1 - alpha) : mc[];
    };

    identities
    {
        # Perfect competition
        mc[] = 1;
    };

    calibration
    {
	L[ss] / K[ss] = 0.36 -> alpha;
    };
};

The alpha parameter is set so that in the steady state, the ratio of labor to capital is 0.36. On the back end, gEconpy will use an optimizer to find a value of alpha that satsifies the user's condition. Note that calibrated parameters cannot have prior distributions!

Lagrange Multipliers and First Order Conditions

As mentioned, all constraints will automatically have a Lagrange multiplier assigned to them. The user name these multipliers himself by putting a colon ":" after an equation, followed by the Lagrange multipler name. From the code above:

C[] + I[] = r[] * K[-1] + w[] * L[] : lambda[];
K[] = (1 - delta) * K[-1] + I[] : q[];

The multiplier associated with the budget constraint has been given the name "lambda", as is usual in the literature, while the law of motion of capital has been given the name q[]. If the user wanted, she could use these variables in further computations within the block, for example Q[] = q[] / lambda[], Tobin's Q, could be added in the identities block.

Interally, first order conditions are solved by first making all substitutions from definitions, then forming the following Lagrangian function: L = objective.RHS - lm1 * (control_1.LHS - control_1.RHS) - lm2 * (control_2.LHS - control_2.RHS) ... - lm_k * (control_k.LHS - control_k.RHS)

Next, the derivative of this Lagrangian is taken with respect to all control variables and all lagrange multipliers. Derivaties are are computed "though time" using TimeAwareSymbols, an extension of a normal Sympy symbol. For a control variable x, the total derivative over time is built up as dL[]/dx[] + beta * dL[+1]/dx + beta * beta * dL[+2]/dx[] .... This unrolling terminates when dL[+n]/dx[] = 0.

The result of this unrolling and taking derivatives process are the first order conditions (FoC). All model FoCs, along with objectives, constraints, and identities, are saved into the system of equations that represents the model.

Steady State

After finding FoCs, the system will be ready to find a steady state and solve for a first-order linear approximation. To help the process, the user can write a STEADY_STATE block. This is a special reserved keyword block that can be placed anywhere in the GCN file. It should contain only defintions and identities as components. Here is an example of a steady state block for the RBC model:

block STEADY_STATE
{
    definitions
    {
      # If this is empty you can delete this, but it is also nice for writing common parameter or variable combinations.
    };

    identities
    {
        A[ss] = 1;
        P[ss] = 1;
        r[ss] = P[ss] * (1 / beta - (1 - delta));
        w[ss] = (1 - alpha) * P[ss] ^ (1 / (1 - alpha)) * (alpha / r[ss]) ^ (alpha / (1 - alpha));
        Y[ss] = (r[ss] / (r[ss] - delta * alpha)) ^ (sigma_C / (sigma_C + sigma_L)) *
            (w[ss] / P[ss] * (w[ss] / P[ss] / (1 - alpha)) ^ sigma_L) ^ (1 / (sigma_C + sigma_L));

        I[ss] = (delta * alpha / r[ss]) * Y[ss];
        C[ss] = Y[ss] ^ (-sigma_L / sigma_C) * ((1 - alpha) ^ (-sigma_L) * (w[ss] / P[ss]) ^ (1 + sigma_L)) ^ (1 / sigma_C);
        K[ss] = alpha * Y[ss] * P[ss] / r[ss];
        L[ss] = (1 - alpha) * Y[ss] * P[ss] / w[ss];


        U[ss] = (1 / (1 - beta)) * (C[ss] ^ (1 - sigma_C) / (1 - sigma_C) - L[ss] ^ (1 + sigma_L) / (1 + sigma_L));
        lambda[ss] = C[ss] ^ (-sigma_C) / P[ss];
        q[ss] = lambda[ss];
        TC[ss] = -(r[ss] * K[ss] + w[ss] * L[ss]);
    };
};

It is not necessary to write an empty definitions component; this was done just to show where it goes. All information from the model block, including parameters and variables, are available to use in the STEADY_STATE block regardless of where they appear relative to each other (you can put the STEADY_STATE block at the top if you wish -- the file is not parsed top-to-bottom).

Note that these equations are not checked in any way -- if you put something in the STEADY_STATE block, it is taken as the Word of God, and model solving proceeds from there. If you are having trouble finding a steady state, be sure to double check these equations.

Finally, you do not have to provide the complete steady state system! You can include only equations, and the rest will be passed to an optimizer to be solved.

Solving the model

Once a GCN file is written, using gEcon to do analysis is easy, as this code block shows:

file_path = 'GCN Files/RBC_basic.gcn'
model = gEconModel(file_path, verbose=True)

When the model is loaded, you will get a message about the number of equations and variables, as well as some other basic model descriptions. You can then solve for the stead state:

model.steady_state()
>>> Steady state found! Sum of squared residuals is 2.9196536232567403e-19

And get the linearized state space representation

model.solve_model()
>>>Solution found, sum of squared residuals:  7.075155451456433e-30
>>>Norm of deterministic part: 0.000000000
>>>Norm of stochastic part:    0.000000000

To see how to do simulations, IRFs, and compute moments, see the example notebook.

Other Features

Dynare Code Generation

Since Dynare is still the gold standard in DSGE modeling, and this is a wacky open source package written by a literally who?, gEconpy has the ability to automatically convert a solved model into a Dynare mod file. This is done as follows:

from gEconpy.shared.dynare_convert import make_mod_file
print(make_mod_file(model))

Output:

var A, C, I, K, L, TC, U, Y, mc, q, r, var_lambda, w;
varexo epsilon_A;

parameters param_alpha, param_beta, param_delta, rho_A;
parameters sigma_C, sigma_L;

param_alpha = 0.35;
param_beta = 0.99;
param_delta = 0.02;
rho_A = 0.95;
sigma_C = 1.5;
sigma_L = 2.0;

model;
-C - I + K(-1) * r + L * w = 0;
I - K + K(-1) *(1 - param_delta) = 0;
C ^(1 - sigma_C) /(1 - sigma_C) - L ^(sigma_L + 1) /(sigma_L + 1) - U + U(1) * param_beta = 0;
-var_lambda + C ^(- sigma_C) = 0;
-L ^ sigma_L + var_lambda * w = 0;
q - var_lambda = 0;
param_beta *(q(1) *(1 - param_delta) + r(1) * var_lambda(1)) - q = 0;
1 - mc = 0;
A * K(-1) ^ param_alpha * L ^(1 - param_alpha) - Y = 0;
-K(-1) * r - L * w - TC = 0;
A * K(-1) ^(param_alpha - 1) * L ^(1 - param_alpha) * param_alpha * mc - r = 0;
A * K(-1) ^ param_alpha * mc *(1 - param_alpha) / L ^ param_alpha - w = 0;
epsilon_A + rho_A * log(A(-1)) - log(A) = 0;
end;

initval;
A = 1.0000;
C = 2.3584;
I = 0.7146;
K = 35.7323;
L = 0.8201;
TC = -3.0731;
U = -148.6156;
Y = 3.0731;
var_lambda = 0.2761;
mc = 1.0000;
q = 0.2761;
r = 0.0301;
w = 2.4358;
end;

steady;
check(qz_zero_threshold=1e-20);

shocks;
var epsilon_A;
stderr 0.01;
end;

stoch_simul(order=1, irf=100, qz_zero_threshold=1e-20);

Warings about Dynare Code

  • No efforts are made to provide symbolic solutions to the steady-state! If you include steady state values in your equations and do not provide a symbolic solution in the STEADY_STATE block, the .mod file will not work "out of the box".
  • If your model includes calibrated equations, the generated Dynare code will not work out of the box. You need to analyically compute the steady state values and add a deterministic relationship (that beings with #) to the model block.

Estimation

Coming soon!

Project details


Download files

Download the file for your platform. If you're not sure which to choose, learn more about installing packages.

Source Distribution

gEconpy-1.2.1.tar.gz (152.0 kB view hashes)

Uploaded Source

Built Distribution

gEconpy-1.2.1-py3-none-any.whl (142.1 kB view hashes)

Uploaded Python 3

Supported by

AWS AWS Cloud computing and Security Sponsor Datadog Datadog Monitoring Fastly Fastly CDN Google Google Download Analytics Microsoft Microsoft PSF Sponsor Pingdom Pingdom Monitoring Sentry Sentry Error logging StatusPage StatusPage Status page